The last of the five strategies for comparison of investment strategies is benefit/cost ratio. This method is commonly used for public planning, by national or local governments, rather than by individual companies. Although there are significant differences between planning in the public and private sectors, the benefit/cost ratio is neutral with respect to these differences, giving the same result as would the present worth or rate of return methods.
Formally, the benefit/cost ratio is defined as the fraction
Present worth of benefits/Present worth of costs
If this ratio is greater than unity, the project should go ahead, otherwise not.
One apparent pitfall in this method is some ambiguity in what should be considered a cost and what a benefit. For example, a project with startup costs C which generates annual revenue R and which must meet annual costs K could be described as having equivalent costs C + K(P/A,i,N) and equivalent benefits R(P/A,i,N). So the B/C ratio would be
R(P/A,i,N)/(C+K(P/A,i,N))
On the other hand, the same project could be considered as yielding an annual profit of P = R-K. This annual profit is certainly a benefit, so we could argue that the benefit/cost ratio should be
(R-K)(P/A,i,N)/C
But these two ratios are different, so how can we decide which to use?
Fortunately, we don't need to decide. The only thing we care about is whether the ratio is greater than 1, and it can be shown that when one of these fractions meets that criterion, so does the other.
This means that the benefit/cost ratio cannot be used to rank alternative strategies in order of preference. However, it can be used to rank incremental strategies in order of preference. This is just the same approach as we used with the rate of return methods: we tabulate the cash-flows of each mutually exclusive option, in increasing order of initial investment, then construct the additional options of upgrading from each viable alternative to its more expensive neighbours. We upgrade whenever the benefit/cost ratio of spending the extra money is greater than unity.
Some of the factors which can be ignored in a private-sector analysis become the responsibility of government by default. For example, the effect on public health of dioxin emissions from a pulp mill can be ignored by the mill owners, since it isn't the job of the pulp industry to look after people's health. If the government does not take responsibility for these factors, known as `externalities', then they will be invisible to the economy -- that is, the economy will act as though clean air and water are of no value.
Such externalities can also occur within government, as, for example, when the Ministry of Transport fulfills its mandate to provide efficient transportation by planning a highway through a forest defined by the Ministry of the Environment as an area of outstanding natural beauty.
On the plus side, governments can usually obtain very favourable interest rates for borrowing money, since it is rare for entire nations to declare bankruptcy.
The economic analysis methods we have discussed here are only a small part of the considerations that should be taken into account in public decision making. It may be desirable to poll public opinion on a controversial project, and the public's wishes may take precedence over the results of analysis. Some of the broader issues are discussed in ``How to Use Cost-Benefit Analysis in Project Appraisal'', M.J. Frost, John Wiley and Sons, 1971 [TA 177.7 F76] and ``The Economics of Environmental Protection'', D. N. Thompson, Winthrop Publishers, 1973 [TD 180 T49].
Despite these very sensible criticisms of the payback-period method, I have noticed that many of the successful entrepreneurs who have given guest lectures in the Wednesday evening slot of this class have, when asked how they evaluate competing proposals, replied that they use the payback-period method. And I have been reluctant to point out their foolishness, since they have often made two or three orders of magnitude more money than I have. Possibly the explanation lies in the field of risk management, which we haven't discussed yet: the reliability of our estimates of future cashflows is lower the further we look into the future, so investors like to know that they'll have recouped their investment by a definite date in the near future.